Alternate Timelines

What If The Chicago School of Economics Never Gained Prominence?

Exploring the alternate timeline where the free-market economic theories of Milton Friedman and the Chicago School never achieved their transformative influence on global economic policy, potentially altering the course of neoliberalism, global development, and inequality.

The Actual History

The Chicago School of Economics, centered at the University of Chicago's Department of Economics, emerged as one of the most influential economic paradigms of the 20th century. While its foundations were established earlier, the school rose to prominence in the post-World War II era under the leadership of scholars like Milton Friedman, George Stigler, Gary Becker, and Ronald Coase. What began as an academic movement eventually transformed global economic policy and reshaped the relationship between governments and markets worldwide.

The intellectual roots of the Chicago School trace back to the 1930s with economists like Frank Knight, Jacob Viner, and Henry Simons, who advocated for free markets during the Great Depression when Keynesian interventionist policies were ascendant. However, it was during the 1950s and 1960s that the school developed its most distinctive characteristics: a strong belief in the efficacy of free markets, skepticism toward government intervention, monetarist theory, and rigorous mathematical and empirical approaches.

Milton Friedman, who joined the University of Chicago in 1946, became the school's most recognizable figure. His 1957 work "A Theory of the Consumption Function" challenged Keynesian assumptions, but it was his 1963 book with Anna Schwartz, "A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960," that fundamentally altered economic thinking. By arguing that the Great Depression was primarily caused by misguided Federal Reserve policies rather than inherent market failures, Friedman provided intellectual ammunition against Keynesian economics.

The Chicago School gained further momentum in the 1970s as the post-war Keynesian consensus faced the challenge of stagflation—the simultaneous occurrence of high inflation and economic stagnation. Traditional Keynesian models struggled to explain this phenomenon, while Friedman's monetarist explanations, which had predicted that excessive monetary expansion would lead to inflation, seemed vindicated. Friedman's 1968 presidential address to the American Economic Association, which introduced the concept of the natural rate of unemployment and questioned the long-term efficacy of Phillips curve trade-offs between inflation and unemployment, became particularly influential.

The school's rise to political prominence came in the late 1970s and 1980s. In Chile, after Augusto Pinochet's 1973 coup, Chicago-trained economists (the "Chicago Boys") implemented free-market reforms. In the United States and United Kingdom, the elections of Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher brought Chicago School principles into mainstream policy. Both leaders embraced deregulation, privatization, tax cuts, and monetarist approaches to controlling inflation. Paul Volcker's Federal Reserve, influenced by monetarist thinking, dramatically raised interest rates to combat inflation in the early 1980s.

The influence of the Chicago School spread globally through international institutions like the International Monetary Fund and World Bank, which increasingly prescribed "Washington Consensus" policies—fiscal discipline, market liberalization, and privatization—to developing nations. The collapse of the Soviet Union further strengthened the perception that free-market economics had triumphed over centrally planned alternatives.

By the early 21st century, Chicago School principles had become deeply embedded in economic policymaking worldwide. However, the 2008 financial crisis prompted renewed questioning of these ideas, as the crisis occurred in highly deregulated financial markets. Critics argued that the Chicago School's faith in efficient markets and rational actors had contributed to regulatory failures. Nevertheless, the school's impact on tax policy, central banking, regulatory approaches, and economic methodology remains profound, making it one of the most consequential intellectual movements of the modern era.

The Point of Divergence

What if the Chicago School of Economics never gained prominence? In this alternate timeline, we explore a scenario where the free-market economic theories associated with Milton Friedman and his colleagues at the University of Chicago remained a minority viewpoint rather than becoming the dominant paradigm in economic policy from the 1970s onward.

Several plausible divergence points could have prevented the Chicago School's rise to prominence:

Academic leadership shifts: One possibility centers on Milton Friedman himself. If Friedman had not joined the University of Chicago in 1946—perhaps accepting a position at Columbia University where he had earned his PhD—the critical mass of free-market thinkers might never have coalesced at Chicago. Alternatively, if George Stigler had remained at Columbia rather than moving to Chicago in 1958, the school would have lacked one of its most influential proponents of microeconomic deregulation.

The monetarist challenge falters: The empirical foundation of the Chicago School's challenge to Keynesianism might have proven weaker. If Friedman and Schwartz's "A Monetary History of the United States" had contained methodological flaws that academic reviewers identified, or if their interpretation of the Great Depression had been more effectively contested, their critique of prevailing economic orthodoxy might have gained less traction.

Stagflation finds a Keynesian solution: The economic conditions of the 1970s—particularly stagflation—created a crisis for mainstream Keynesian economics and an opening for Chicago School alternatives. If post-Keynesian economists had developed more effective responses to stagflation, perhaps by incorporating supply-side factors into their models earlier or developing more sophisticated explanations for the Phillips curve breakdown, policymakers might not have turned to monetarist alternatives.

The Chile experiment fails dramatically: The implementation of Chicago School policies by Pinochet's regime in Chile, guided by Chicago-trained economists, served as an influential test case. If these policies had resulted in a more visible economic disaster rather than the "Chilean economic miracle" narrative that developed (despite significant social costs), the reputation of Chicago School prescriptions would have been severely damaged.

In our alternate timeline, we'll focus on a combination of these factors—particularly a weaker empirical foundation for monetarism and more adaptive Keynesian responses to 1970s economic challenges—creating a world where the Chicago School remains one academic approach among many rather than becoming the foundation for a global policy revolution. Without this intellectual foundation, the neoliberal turn in economic policy would take a dramatically different form—or perhaps not occur at all.

Immediate Aftermath

The Persistence of Post-War Keynesianism

In this alternate timeline, the Keynesian consensus that dominated Western economic policy after World War II proves more resilient in the face of 1970s challenges. Without the Chicago School's influential critique, economic thinking evolves differently:

Adaptive Keynesianism emerges: Rather than being displaced by monetarism, Keynesian economics adapts to the stagflation challenge. Economists like James Tobin at Yale University and Nicholas Kaldor at Cambridge University develop more sophisticated Keynesian models that incorporate both monetary factors and supply-side constraints. Their "Neo-Keynesian Synthesis" acknowledges the importance of monetary policy while maintaining a role for fiscal intervention and incomes policies to manage inflation.

Alternative explanations for stagflation gain traction: Without Friedman's natural rate hypothesis dominating the debate, alternative explanations for the breakdown of the Phillips curve receive more attention. Economists focus more intensely on supply shocks—particularly oil price spikes—and the role of institutional factors in wage-price spirals. This leads to more targeted interventions rather than the wholesale abandonment of demand management.

The Federal Reserve takes a different path: Paul Volcker's appointment as Federal Reserve Chairman in 1979 still occurs, but without the strong influence of monetarist thinking, his approach to fighting inflation differs substantially. Rather than focusing exclusively on controlling monetary aggregates regardless of interest rate consequences, the Fed pursues a more gradual tightening combined with coordinated wage-price policies. The extreme recession of 1981-82 is less severe, though inflation takes longer to fully subdue.

The Politics of Economic Policy (1976-1985)

The political landscape shifts considerably without the Chicago School's influence:

The Carter administration pursues different policies: President Jimmy Carter, facing stagflation but without the rising tide of monetarist thinking, does not deregulate industries as extensively. His appointment of Volcker still signals commitment to fighting inflation, but the administration simultaneously implements a more comprehensive incomes policy, negotiating wage and price guidelines with major industries and labor unions. While still facing economic challenges, Carter's approach appears more coherent without the conflicting pressures of emerging neoliberalism.

Different conservative responses emerge: When Ronald Reagan campaigns for president in 1980, his economic platform lacks the coherent free-market narrative provided by Chicago School thinking. While still advocating tax cuts, his administration doesn't embrace the comprehensive deregulation agenda that characterized his actual presidency. Similarly, in the UK, Margaret Thatcher's economic program has a more nationalist and pragmatic character rather than a principled free-market orientation. Both leaders focus more on fighting specific instances of government waste and inefficiency rather than a wholesale philosophical attack on government's economic role.

International institutions maintain development orthodoxy: Without Chicago School influence permeating the IMF and World Bank, these institutions continue emphasizing infrastructure development, import substitution, and industrial policy rather than pivoting to structural adjustment programs focused on liberalization and privatization. Developing nations continue receiving loans with fewer conditions regarding market reforms.

The Chilean Counter-Example

The fate of Chile becomes particularly significant in this timeline:

A cautionary tale instead of a model: Without the intellectual backing of the Chicago School, the economic policies implemented after Pinochet's coup follow a different path. Rather than being guided by Chicago-trained economists advocating comprehensive liberalization, the regime implements a more conventional authoritarian developmentalist model, combining state-led industrialization with political repression (similar to South Korea or Taiwan). When this approach struggles with the oil shocks and debt crisis of the late 1970s, it reinforces skepticism about associating free markets with development.

Latin American development takes a different path: Without the "Chilean miracle" narrative influencing development thinking, Latin American countries facing debt crises in the early 1980s receive different policy advice. Instead of the Washington Consensus prescriptions of privatization and liberalization, international institutions promote more gradual reforms emphasizing export promotion alongside continued state coordination. Mexico, Brazil, and Argentina implement heterodox stabilization plans combining selective market reforms with strategic industrial policies.

Academic Economics Evolves Differently

The field of economics itself develops along different lines without the Chicago School's dominance:

Methodological pluralism persists: Without Chicago's emphasis on mathematical modeling and efficient markets becoming as dominant, economic methodology remains more diverse. Institutional and historical approaches maintain greater prestige within the discipline, and behavioral perspectives challenging the rational actor model emerge earlier and more prominently.

Development economics remains structuralist: The field of development economics continues its structuralist orientation, emphasizing the role of institutions, power imbalances, and strategic state intervention rather than embracing market fundamentalism. Economists like Albert Hirschman, Hollis Chenery, and Arthur Lewis maintain greater influence compared to free-market proponents.

By the mid-1980s, the global economic landscape looks noticeably different—economic thinking embraces a more pragmatic, interventionist approach, and the sharp neoliberal turn of our timeline has been replaced by a more evolutionary adaptation of the post-war consensus.

Long-term Impact

Alternative Economic Paradigms (1985-2000)

Without the Chicago School's dominance, a different economic paradigm takes shape by the end of the 20th century:

The Managed Market Synthesis: Rather than a neoliberal consensus emphasizing deregulation and minimal government, economic thinking coalesces around what becomes known as the "Managed Market Synthesis." This approach recognizes the importance of market mechanisms while maintaining a substantial role for government in addressing market failures, managing macroeconomic cycles, and ensuring equitable outcomes. Economists like Joseph Stiglitz, Amartya Sen, and Robert Reich become the leading public intellectuals rather than free-market advocates.

Industrial Policy Remains Legitimate: Without Chicago School skepticism toward government's ability to "pick winners," strategic industrial policy maintains intellectual legitimacy in advanced economies. The success of countries like Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan—which combined market orientation with strategic state guidance—becomes the model that influences Western economic thinking. The United States establishes an Industrial Strategy Board in 1988, which coordinates research and development investments in emerging technologies, particularly computing and renewable energy.

Different Regulatory Evolution: Financial regulation follows a drastically different trajectory. Without the Chicago School's efficient market hypothesis undermining the case for robust oversight, the financial deregulation that characterized the 1990s never occurs on the same scale. The Glass-Steagall separation between commercial and investment banking remains intact, and derivatives markets develop under greater regulatory scrutiny. While financial innovation still occurs, it does so within a more structured framework emphasizing systemic stability.

Altered Global Economic Integration

The process of globalization unfolds differently without the free-market orthodoxy of the Chicago School:

Managed Trade Rather Than Free Trade: International trade agreements evolve with greater emphasis on managing trade relationships rather than simply removing barriers. The Uruguay Round negotiations (1986-1994) produce a more limited World Trade Organization that preserves greater policy space for developing countries to pursue industrial strategies. Regional trade agreements include stronger provisions for labor and environmental standards from the outset.

Different Approach to Capital Flows: Without the influence of Chicago School ideas promoting capital account liberalization as unambiguously beneficial, international financial institutions advocate more cautious approaches to international capital flows. The IMF endorses strategic capital controls to manage volatile short-term flows, and developing countries maintain greater autonomy in managing their integration into global financial markets. The Asian Financial Crisis of 1997-1998 is less severe as countries like Thailand, Indonesia, and South Korea have more tools to manage speculative attacks on their currencies.

Alternative Development Paths: Developing nations pursue more diverse economic strategies without the pressure to conform to Washington Consensus prescriptions. Some Latin American countries implement hybrid models combining selective market orientation with strategic state intervention and robust social welfare systems. Brazil, under this timeline's version of President Fernando Henrique Cardoso, pursues a "social democratic development" model that achieves more inclusive growth than the market-oriented reforms of our timeline.

Economic Inequality Trajectories

One of the most significant long-term differences involves patterns of economic inequality:

Moderated Inequality in Advanced Economies: Without the Chicago School's influence on tax policy, corporate governance, and labor market deregulation, the dramatic rise in inequality seen in the United States and United Kingdom from the 1980s onward is substantially moderated. Top marginal tax rates remain higher, around 50-60% rather than falling to 28% under Reagan, and capital gains continue to be taxed similarly to ordinary income. Corporate governance maintains a stronger stakeholder orientation rather than focusing exclusively on shareholder value.

Stronger Labor Institutions: Labor unions experience a less dramatic decline in this timeline. Without the Chicago School's argument that unions primarily distort labor markets rather than correct power imbalances, policy remains more supportive of collective bargaining. In the United States, labor law reforms in the late 1980s strengthen organizing rights, while European countries maintain stronger employment protections. This contributes to wage growth remaining more closely tied to productivity gains.

Different Welfare State Evolution: Rather than the retrenchment of welfare states that characterized the neoliberal era, advanced economies in this timeline pursue modernization and adaptation of social programs. Universal basic services expand in healthcare and education, while innovative approaches to social insurance develop to address new forms of work and social risks. Scandinavian models of "flexicurity"—combining labor market flexibility with strong social safety nets—become more influential globally.

Technology and Innovation in a Different Economic Environment

The technological landscape evolves differently without Chicago School influence:

Public-Private Innovation Ecosystems: Government maintains a more active role in technology development, with expanded funding for basic research and strategic investments in emerging technologies. The internet still emerges from DARPA research, but subsequent development follows a more mixed model with greater public input on standards and infrastructure. Biotechnology advances through coordinated national research initiatives alongside private sector innovation.

Different Digital Economy Regulation: When digital platforms emerge in the 1990s and 2000s, they develop in a regulatory environment that never embraced the Chicago School's permissive approach to antitrust. Consequently, digital markets evolve with stronger guardrails preventing winner-take-all outcomes. Major technology companies face earlier and more effective interventions to preserve competition, resulting in more diverse digital ecosystems rather than the emergence of a few dominant platforms.

The Global Financial Crisis and Beyond (2007-2025)

The defining economic events of the early 21st century unfold differently:

A Milder Financial Crisis: Without the extensive deregulation of financial markets that the Chicago School influenced, the housing bubble that developed in the early 2000s is smaller and less leveraged. When the correction comes in 2007-2008, it causes a recession but not the catastrophic financial crisis of our timeline. Financial institutions have maintained higher capital requirements and less complex interconnections, allowing for a more orderly adjustment. Central banks still intervene with liquidity support, but massive bailouts are unnecessary.

Climate Policy Develops Earlier: Without the Chicago School's skepticism toward government intervention and preference for market-only solutions, more robust climate policies emerge earlier. Carbon pricing mechanisms combined with strategic green industrial policies become mainstream by the early 2000s, accelerating the transition to renewable energy. By 2025, this timeline sees dramatically higher renewable energy penetration and lower carbon emissions, with climate change remaining a challenge but a less dire one.

Pandemic Response Shows Different Priorities: When COVID-19 strikes in 2020, economic response policies reflect different values than in our timeline. Rather than focusing primarily on maintaining asset prices and providing business liquidity, governments implement more comprehensive support directly to households and workers. Public health systems, having benefited from continued investment rather than austerity, demonstrate greater resilience in managing the crisis.

By 2025, this alternate timeline features more balanced economic growth, moderately lower absolute GDP but significantly more equitable distribution, stronger social safety nets, and more proactive approaches to collective challenges like climate change. Technology has advanced somewhat more slowly in some areas but more democratically, with benefits more widely shared. The global economic system exhibits greater diversity of national approaches rather than convergence on a single model, with more emphasis on stability and inclusion alongside efficiency.

Expert Opinions

Dr. Jessica Marten, Professor of Economic History at Princeton University, offers this perspective: "The Chicago School provided the intellectual architecture for a fundamental reorientation of economic priorities in the late 20th century—from shared prosperity to efficiency and growth above all else. In a timeline where this framework never gained prominence, we likely would have seen continued evolution of the mixed economy rather than its partial dismantling. The most profound difference would be in how we understand the relationship between markets and democracy—without Chicago's influence, markets would more likely be seen as tools to be shaped by democratic priorities rather than as embodiments of freedom themselves."

Professor Luis Rodriguez, Director of the Center for Development Economics at Oxford University, suggests: "The dominance of Chicago School thinking dramatically narrowed the policy space considered legitimate for developing countries. Where once multiple development pathways were recognized—from East Asian state-led industrialization to Nordic social democracy—after the 1980s, a single prescription of liberalization, privatization, and deregulation was promoted regardless of context. In an alternate timeline where this intellectual monopoly never emerged, we would likely see much greater diversity in development strategies and more emphasis on context-specific institutions. The irony is that while Chicago economists rhetorically championed diversity and choice in markets, their dominance actually reduced the diversity of economic thinking and policy experimentation."

Dr. Elaine Chen, Senior Fellow at the Global Economy Institute, notes: "What's often overlooked is how the Chicago School's rise changed the very language and metrics of economic success. Economic discourse shifted from broad measures of social welfare to narrow metrics like inflation rates and GDP growth. In a world where their influence remained limited, we would likely evaluate economic performance differently—giving greater weight to employment quality, distribution of gains, and sustainability alongside aggregate growth. The current renewed interest in measures beyond GDP might have been the mainstream approach all along rather than a recent corrective. Most significantly, I believe economic inequality would never have reached the extreme levels we see today, as policy would have maintained more countervailing power against market concentration."

Further Reading