Alternate Timelines

What If The Federal Reserve Was Never Created?

Exploring the alternate timeline where the United States never established its central banking system in 1913, potentially reshaping American monetary policy, economic development, and global financial influence throughout the 20th and 21st centuries.

The Actual History

The Federal Reserve System—America's central banking system—was created on December 23, 1913, when President Woodrow Wilson signed the Federal Reserve Act into law. The establishment of the Fed, as it is commonly known, came after a series of financial panics that plagued the United States throughout the 19th and early 20th centuries. These crises, particularly the severe Panic of 1907, highlighted the instability of the American financial system and the need for a central authority to manage the money supply and provide stability.

Prior to the Fed's creation, the United States had experimented with two earlier central banks—the First Bank of the United States (1791-1811) and the Second Bank of the United States (1816-1836). Both institutions were controversial and ultimately lost their charters amid political opposition, particularly from those who feared centralized financial power. After the Second Bank's demise during Andrew Jackson's presidency, America experienced a "free banking era" where individual states chartered banks with limited oversight.

The push for a new central bank gained momentum following the Panic of 1907, when financial markets collapsed and a severe liquidity crisis emerged. The absence of a central institution forced financier J.P. Morgan to step in, organizing private bankers to inject funds into the market and essentially acting as a lender of last resort—a role typically played by central banks. This crisis prompted the establishment of the National Monetary Commission, which studied banking systems worldwide and recommended the creation of a central banking authority.

The resulting Federal Reserve Act established a system with both public and private elements—a compromise designed to balance government oversight with banking sector involvement. The Fed was structured as a system of twelve regional Federal Reserve Banks overseen by a Federal Reserve Board appointed by the president.

Since its founding, the Federal Reserve has evolved considerably in its responsibilities and operations. Initially focused primarily on providing an "elastic currency" and serving as a lender of last resort, the Fed's mandate expanded significantly following the Great Depression. The Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935 strengthened the Fed's powers and centralized authority in Washington. In 1977, Congress formalized the Fed's "dual mandate" of promoting maximum employment and stable prices.

Throughout its history, the Federal Reserve has played a pivotal role during economic crises. During the Great Depression, the Fed was criticized for not acting aggressively enough to prevent bank failures and monetary contraction. Learning from this experience, the Fed took more decisive action during subsequent crises, including the 2008 financial crisis and the COVID-19 pandemic, when it deployed extraordinary measures to stabilize markets and support economic activity.

Today, the Federal Reserve serves as the nation's monetary policy authority, a regulator of financial institutions, and the operator of payment systems. Its decisions on interest rates and money supply influence economic conditions not only in the United States but globally. The Fed's independence—its ability to make decisions without direct political interference—has become a defining characteristic, though this independence has remained a source of ongoing debate.

The Point of Divergence

What if the Federal Reserve was never created? In this alternate timeline, we explore a scenario where the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 failed to become law, leaving the United States without a central banking system throughout the turbulent 20th century and beyond.

Several plausible scenarios could have prevented the Fed's establishment:

First, the political dynamics in 1913 could have shifted against centralized banking. President Woodrow Wilson was instrumental in navigating the Federal Reserve Act through Congress, but had he taken a different stance—perhaps influenced by the traditionally Democratic skepticism of central banking—the bill might have failed. Wilson came to office with complex views on banking reform, and if he had allied more closely with the populist wing of his party that was suspicious of Wall Street influence, he might have opposed the Federal Reserve Act or demanded changes that made it unacceptable to enough legislators.

Alternatively, the alliance between Progressive Republicans and Democrats that supported the Federal Reserve Act could have fractured. The bill passed the House by 298 to 60 and the Senate by 43 to 25, but these margins might have narrowed significantly if compromises on the structure and governance of the system had fallen apart. Banking interests, who pushed for a privately controlled central bank, and agrarian populists, who feared such an institution would serve financial elites, maintained an uneasy compromise in the actual legislation. Had either group pushed harder for their preferences, the coalition supporting the bill might have collapsed.

A third possibility involves the influence of powerful financial figures like J.P. Morgan. While Morgan had demonstrated the need for a lender of last resort during the Panic of 1907, some financial elites actually opposed the Federal Reserve's creation, fearing government oversight would limit their autonomy. If more Wall Street bankers had actively opposed the legislation, they might have successfully lobbied enough congressmen to block its passage.

In this alternate timeline, we assume that heightened populist sentiment combined with disagreements over the Federal Reserve's structure ultimately derailed the legislation in late 1913. President Wilson, facing stronger-than-expected opposition from both progressive and conservative elements, was unable to secure passage before the congressional session ended. Subsequent attempts to revive the legislation faded as other priorities—particularly World War I after 1914—consumed the administration's attention. As a result, America continued with its decentralized banking system, relying on the existing national banking system established during the Civil War, supplemented by various patchwork reforms.

Without this crucial institutional innovation, the United States would face the economic challenges of the 20th century with a fundamentally different financial architecture, altering the course of American and global economic history.

Immediate Aftermath

Banking System Adaptations (1914-1919)

Without the Federal Reserve, the existing National Banking System would have continued operating, but its weaknesses—inelastic currency supply and decentralized reserves—would have remained unaddressed. In the absence of comprehensive reform, Congress likely would have implemented more limited measures to address the most glaring deficiencies.

One probable development would have been an expansion of the Aldrich-Vreeland Act of 1908, which had been passed as a temporary measure following the Panic of 1907 to allow banks to issue emergency currency backed by various securities during financial crises. Originally set to expire in 1914, this act would likely have been renewed and potentially expanded in our alternate timeline.

The Treasury Department would have taken on greater responsibility for managing currency issues and providing emergency liquidity. Treasury Secretary William Gibbs McAdoo, who in actual history served as the first Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, would instead have focused on strengthening the Treasury's capacity to intervene in financial markets directly.

Private clearinghouse associations—consortiums of banks that had historically cooperated during panics—would have formalized their operations further. Major financial centers like New York, Chicago, and San Francisco might have established more permanent clearinghouse institutions with expanded powers to coordinate during crises, effectively creating a private, decentralized version of some central banking functions.

World War I Financing Challenges (1917-1919)

The absence of a Federal Reserve would have created significant challenges for American war financing after the U.S. entered World War I in 1917. In our actual timeline, the Federal Reserve helped manage the massive Liberty Bond drives that raised over $17 billion for the war effort and coordinated with banks to ensure sufficient liquidity.

Without this central coordination, the Wilson administration would have had to rely more heavily on direct Treasury operations and the private banking sector. This likely would have resulted in less efficient bond sales and potentially higher interest rates on government debt, increasing the cost of war financing.

The lack of a central bank would have complicated international financial cooperation with allies. In actual history, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, under Benjamin Strong, worked closely with the Bank of England and other European central banks on currency stabilization and war finance. Without this institution, international monetary coordination would have been more difficult and likely conducted through ad hoc arrangements between the Treasury Department and foreign finance ministries.

Post-War Recession (1919-1921)

The post-World War I recession, which was severe in actual history, would likely have been more pronounced without the Federal Reserve. The recession of 1919-1921 saw consumer prices fall by nearly 50% as the economy transitioned from wartime to peacetime production. In our timeline, the Federal Reserve raised interest rates significantly to combat post-war inflation, contributing to the recession's severity.

In the alternate timeline, without a central bank to manage this transition, the economic adjustment would have been more chaotic. The inability to coordinate monetary policy nationally would have likely resulted in:

  • Wildly varying interest rates across regions as individual banks responded differently to economic conditions
  • More bank failures as institutions couldn't access emergency liquidity
  • Greater deflation as the money supply contracted more severely during the downturn
  • Longer duration of the recession due to the absence of coordinated policy response

The more severe economic dislocation might have fueled greater political discontent, potentially strengthening progressive and populist movements advocating for more dramatic financial reforms. The actual historical debates about returning to the gold standard and international monetary stabilization would have been even more contentious without a central institution to implement such policies.

International Financial Position (1919-1923)

By 1919, the United States had emerged as the world's leading creditor nation, a dramatic shift from its pre-war position. Without the Federal Reserve to help manage this transition and coordinate international monetary affairs, America's financial power would have been less cohesively projected.

The international gold standard, which had collapsed during World War I, faced uncertain prospects for restoration. In our actual timeline, the Federal Reserve played a key role in international conferences attempting to restore gold-based currency stability. Without this central institution, the U.S. position in these negotiations would have been weaker and more fragmented, with Treasury officials lacking the same flexibility and authority that Federal Reserve representatives possessed.

By 1923, the lack of centralized banking authority would have cemented a reputation of the American financial system as powerful but institutionally underdeveloped compared to European counterparts. This perception would have significant implications as the world moved toward the unprecedented challenges of the Great Depression.

Long-term Impact

The Great Depression Era (1929-1939)

Banking System Collapse

The stock market crash of 1929 would have triggered an even more catastrophic banking crisis in our alternate timeline. Without the Federal Reserve's discount window (limited though its actual historical use was), banks would have had no institutionalized lender of last resort. The waves of bank failures that occurred between 1930 and 1933—which were severe even with the Federal Reserve in existence—would have been significantly worse.

By 1933, instead of the approximately 9,000 bank failures that occurred in our timeline, we might have seen the collapse of 12,000-14,000 banks. This would have represented nearly half of all U.S. banks, compared to the roughly one-third that failed in actual history. The banking holiday declared by President Roosevelt in March 1933 would have been preceded by more extensive state-level bank holidays as governors desperately tried to stem the financial bleeding.

Alternative Reform Measures

The severity of the crisis would have forced more radical banking reforms than those enacted in our timeline. The Glass-Steagall Banking Act of 1933, which separated commercial and investment banking and established the FDIC, would likely have been accompanied by the creation of a new central banking authority—essentially establishing the Federal Reserve two decades later than in our timeline, but with a structure far more directly controlled by the federal government.

This "Second Banking Act" might have resembled the originally proposed version of the Federal Reserve with a single, Washington-based central bank rather than the regional system that was adopted in 1913. Given the Depression-era skepticism of bankers, this institution would likely have had minimal private bank involvement and operated essentially as a government agency under Treasury Department oversight.

Monetary Policy Limitations

The absence of the Federal Reserve during the early Depression years would have removed even the limited monetary policy tools that existed in our timeline. The monetary contraction that Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz famously identified as a key cause of the Depression's severity would have been even more pronounced. Without an institution capable of expanding the money supply through open market operations, the deflationary spiral would have cut deeper and lasted longer.

The gold standard might have been abandoned earlier than the actual 1933 departure, as the lack of centralized gold reserves would have made maintaining the standard practically impossible amid bank collapses and international financial pressures.

Post-War Economic Management (1945-1971)

Bretton Woods System Challenges

The 1944 Bretton Woods Conference, which established the post-war international monetary system, would have unfolded quite differently without an established American central bank. The dollar-based fixed exchange rate system that emerged would have required some institutional mechanism for management.

A hastily constructed American central banking authority might have struggled to maintain the credibility needed for the dollar to serve effectively as the world's reserve currency. The International Monetary Fund would likely have played a more central role in managing global liquidity and exchange rate stability, potentially creating a more multilateral system rather than the dollar-dominated arrangement that actually emerged.

Post-War Prosperity and Inflation Challenges

The remarkable economic expansion of the post-war period (1945-1970) might have followed a more volatile trajectory without established central bank management. The "Great Inflation" that began in the late 1960s would have arrived earlier and proven more difficult to control without centralized monetary policy tools.

By the late 1960s, as inflation pressures mounted with Vietnam War spending and expanded social programs, the lack of an independent central bank might have resulted in more direct political manipulation of monetary conditions. Treasury officials, directly accountable to presidential administrations, would have faced immense pressure to accommodate government spending through monetary expansion, potentially leading to earlier and more severe inflation than what occurred in the 1970s of our timeline.

Modern Financial Evolution (1971-2025)

The Nixon Shock and Floating Exchange Rates

The 1971 decision to suspend dollar convertibility to gold (the "Nixon Shock") would have occurred in a different institutional context. Without the Federal Reserve's accumulated expertise in currency management, the transition to floating exchange rates would have been more chaotic, potentially leading to greater currency volatility throughout the 1970s.

The oil price shocks and stagflation of the 1970s would have created even greater economic disruption without an established central bank to manage monetary policy. The eventual inflation-fighting measures might have required more extreme fiscal measures rather than the monetary tightening implemented by Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker in our timeline.

Financial Deregulation and Innovation

The wave of financial deregulation that began in the 1980s would have encountered a different regulatory landscape. Without the Federal Reserve's role in bank supervision, regulatory responsibility would have been more fragmented across agencies like the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency and state banking departments.

Financial innovation might have developed along different lines. The growth of securitization, derivatives, and the shadow banking system might have either accelerated due to regulatory gaps or been more constrained by lack of central bank liquidity support. The financial stability concerns that emerged would have been addressed through different institutional mechanisms.

Crisis Response Capabilities

The most dramatic divergence would appear during financial crises. The 1987 stock market crash, which was contained partly through Federal Reserve liquidity provision, might have escalated into a broader financial crisis. The savings and loan crisis of the late 1980s and early 1990s would have required more direct government bailouts without central bank crisis management tools.

The 2008 Global Financial Crisis would have been catastrophic. Without the extraordinary measures implemented by the Federal Reserve—including emergency liquidity facilities, currency swap lines with foreign central banks, and quantitative easing—the financial system collapse might have triggered a second Great Depression. The Treasury Department would have lacked the tools and flexibility to respond as rapidly as the Federal Reserve did.

Similarly, the economic impact of the COVID-19 pandemic in 2020 would have been significantly worse without a central bank able to implement massive asset purchases, near-zero interest rates, and international coordination with other central banks.

Contemporary Financial Landscape

By 2025 in our alternate timeline, the United States would likely have eventually established some form of central banking authority, but its structure, mandate, and independence would differ substantially from the Federal Reserve we know. It might function more like a government agency with less independence, reflecting the populist suspicions of banker influence that would have persisted throughout the century without being moderated by the Federal Reserve's institutional development.

International financial coordination would operate through different channels, with greater reliance on multilateral institutions rather than central bank cooperation. The dollar might still serve as the world's primary reserve currency, but its position would be less dominant without the institutional backing of an established central bank with a century of credibility.

The absence of the Federal Reserve throughout most of the 20th century would have fundamentally altered American capitalism, likely creating a financial system more prone to boom-bust cycles, more directly influenced by political pressures, and less capable of managing the complex global financial integration that has characterized the modern era.

Expert Opinions

Dr. Christina Romer, former Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers and Professor of Economics at UC Berkeley, offers this perspective: "The absence of the Federal Reserve throughout the crucial early decades of the 20th century would have profoundly altered American economic development. While many economists, myself included, have criticized the Fed's actual performance during the Great Depression, the complete absence of a central bank would have been far worse. Without even the limited tools the Fed provided, the Depression would have been more severe and long-lasting, potentially altering the fundamental relationship between Americans and their government. The New Deal might have included even more dramatic federal interventions in the economy, possibly including nationalization of the banking system rather than just reform."

Mark Calabria, former Director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency and financial historian, presents a contrasting view: "The absence of the Federal Reserve might have prompted the development of more robust private sector mechanisms for maintaining financial stability. The clearinghouse associations, which performed admirably during earlier panics, could have evolved into more sophisticated institutions for managing liquidity needs. While certain crises would undoubtedly have been more severe in the short term, the American financial system might have developed greater resilience through decentralized mechanisms rather than relying on a single central authority. The moral hazard created by the expectation of central bank rescues has arguably made our financial system more crisis-prone in some respects."

Dr. Liaquat Ahamed, Pulitzer Prize-winning author on financial history, suggests: "Without the Federal Reserve, the United States would have faced a significant handicap in projecting financial power globally throughout the 20th century. The international monetary system that emerged after World War II, with the dollar at its center, depended crucially on the institutional framework provided by the Federal Reserve. In its absence, international monetary arrangements would likely have centered more heavily on gold or evolved toward a truly international currency managed by an institution like the IMF. American economic influence would have remained substantial due to the country's industrial might, but its financial influence would have been more constrained and less strategic without the sophisticated operations of a central bank coordinating with counterparts around the world."

Further Reading